Asia’s economic ties with Latin America: NAFTA and China (2)
Second of two parts
In the first part of this article, I recounted the story of the
unlikely creation of NAFTA after Mexico ditched half a century of
inward-looking, protectionist policies and proposed a free trade
agreement to the United States, which eventually turned into the North
American Free Trade Agreement, including Canada, in 1994. Also, we
narrated how soon-after NAFTA’s trade started expanding fast, China’s
entrance into the global world trade when it joined the WTO in 2001,
began competing very effectively with Mexico in the U.S. market, as well
as penetrating Mexico’s own domestic market, slowing the growth of
trade between those two countries both ways. Finally, how this situation
has changed dramatically in the last few years with China’s policies
shifting towards expanding its internal market instead of the aggressive
export-oriented strategy followed in the previous two decades.
China’s
trade with the US and Mexico started growing extremely fast, in such a
way that by 2009 it had become the second largest trading partner of
both countries, a situation that continues until today, but in a very
lopsided manner: China exports to both nations far more of what it
imports from them. Last year the US trade deficit (merchandise) with
China reached $365 billion and around $65 billion with Mexico. This
situation has given rise to protectionist feelings and, in some cases,
by the adoption of countervailing duties, as was recently the case with
steel products in which both countries charged China with dumping.
China losing edge
But these trends that have been the feature of North America’s trade
with China for the last fifteen years are changing fast. China is losing
competitiveness vis-a-vis Mexico because of sharp increases in
wages above gains in productivity growth; as the result of a
demographic tendency towards aging of the Chinese population, that the
new policy to allow an increase the number of children per family will
not change; higher costs of transportation, although the dramatic fall
in the price of oil will ameliorate to some extent this effect; and,
finally, the relative strength of the yuan, versus most other
currencies, including Mexico’s peso, that have depreciated substantially
in the last year and a half.
The share of China’s exports to the US market, which back in 1990 was
only 3.1%, shot-up to almost 20% by 2009 but has been falling to around
15% in the last two years. Meanwhile, the share of Mexico’s exports in
the US market went from 6.1% in 1990 to 13.4% in 2014 and 2015.
Interestingly, the undisputed main trading partner of the US, Canada,
has fallen for the first time in recent history to second place due to
the fall in oil and gas prices. Just between 2014 and 2015, its share
fell from 16.6% to 14.5%, below China’s and slightly above Mexico’s. But
according to projections of the Economist Intelligence Unit by as soon
as 2018 Mexico will be the undisputed largest trading partner of the US,
somewhat above China and more than two percentage points over Canada.
China is becoming less and less a low cost manufacturing base as the
result of a combination of factors that have eroded their cost advantage
considerably in the last few years, and its estimated manufacturing
cost advantage over the US has shrunk to virtually zero over the last
twelve years, which is one of the reasons for the re-industrialization
of that country, and the growing number of manufacturing plants moving
from China to Mexico, in many cases returning back after they left in
the early 2000’s.
Mexico, US cost structures improve
Meanwhile,
cost structures in Mexico and the US improved far more than in the
other 20 largest exporting nations, as the result of low wage growth in
real terms, sustained productivity gains, a relatively weak Mexican peso
in the last 18 months and, even more fundamentally, much lower energy
costs than anywhere else in the world. According to a Boston Consulting
Group’s analysis, the US and Mexico are the current rising stars of
global manufacturing and they estimate that Mexico now has lower costs
than China on a unit-cost basis, and the rest of the world’s top ten
exporters of merchandise – excluding China and Korea — are between 10%
and 25% more expensive than the US.'
China can no longer be considered a low-cost manufacturing base. The
low-cost edge a key advantage for decades that allowed it to conquer the
world export market until it became the US’ largest trading partner,
albeit ephemerally as was mentioned earlier.
But the tables have turned. In the last twelve years, it’s estimated that China’s competitiveness vis-à-vis
the US has shrunk from a 14% lower average cost adjusted for
productivity differences, to virtual parity now, and with regards to
Mexico, China’s competitiveness losses are even sharper. The reasons for
this erosion are clear: skyrocketing labor costs that have more than
tripled with respect to the US and quadrupled in relation to Mexico. The
cost of energy is another key factor: the costs of industrial
electricity and natural gas in China rose by 70% and 138%, respectively,
in the same period, as they remained virtually flat in the US, although
the price of natural gas fell by 50% thanks to the revolution in oil
and gas extraction, while they also fell substantially in Mexico, as the
result of its recently implemented energy sector reforms.
The future for NAFTA and China will depend very much on what happens,
first, with the Trans Pacific Partnership (TPP), which is currently in
the process of ratification by the national legislatures of the twelve
signatory nations. It includes important Asian countries, like Japan and
Vietnam, but not China. Another way to look at TPP, in which both
Canada and Mexico are included, is to bring NAFTA’s protocols up to 21st
century standards and incorporate all the issues that were not included
in the original treaty signed in 1993, either because they were
nonexistent, like cyber-commerce, or were not negotiated then, like
homogenization of national standards in a myriad sectors of the
economies that are today one of the main obstacle to free trade.
It has been suggested that the real hidden political objective of TPP
is to eventually force China to adopt its far more stringent protocols
in many issues, such a competitiveness policy, which TPP intends to
change dramatically by assuring that all participating parties have
similar laws on these matters. These new protocols would replicate those
of the US in issues like consumer protection against fraudulent and
deceptive commercial activities that could harm consumers, and
procedural fairness in the application of the laws, a pending assignment
in some of the TPP nations as well as in China. This chapter of the TPP
negotiation will also ensure convergence in the structure and
application of anti-trust and monopoly-busting rules and regulations.
The other key chapter of the proposed TPP is a much improved set of
rules dealing with state-owned enterprises (SOEs) compared to those
included in NAFTA, which includes commitments by the member nations to
ensure that their SOEs make purchases of goods and services on the basis
of commercial considerations and that they do not discriminate against
the corporations, goods and services of other member countries. Among
the provisions of this chapter, it is required that TPP nations provide
their courts with jurisdiction over commercial activities of foreign
SOEs operating in a TPP country, so they could not evade legal action by
claiming sovereign immunity, providing rules that ensure that their
administrative entities regulating commercial activities do so in an
impartial manner.
Worries about the role of SOEs have grown in the last decades since
they are increasingly operating in the global marketplace rather than
exclusively in their own territories, as used to be the case, as they
are increasingly engaging in international trade and investment. These
provisions will cover subsidies, preferential financing and regulatory
policies that favor SOEs by their national governments, while at the
same time recognizing and ensuring the legitimate role of SOEs in the
provision of public services.
Clearly these radical overhauls of the legal framework and protocols
of the competitiveness and state-owned enterprises in TPP had very much
in mind not only China but also Korea, which are not part of TPP
currently but could join later, and where a veil of ambiguity prevails
in these areas. My bet is that if TPP is ratified by the end of 2016, as
now seems probable, within three years it would expand to incorporate
China and Korea, which would represent the historical reset of North
America towards Asia that the leaders of the NAFTA nations, led by
President Obama, have toiled hard to accomplish.
____________________________________
Manuel Suarez-Mier is a Washington, DC-based
independent consultant on economic and financial issues. He has taught
economics and international finance at various universities in the US
and Mexico and was Director of the Center for North American Studies at
American University 2014-2015. His numerous posts include chief of staff
of the Governor of the Bank of Mexico. He also was Mexico’s top
economic diplomat in Washington at the time of the negotiations of the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) between the US, Canada and
Mexico.